Abstract
This study investigates the impacts of workers’ remittances on poverty and inequality by using data for 103 developing countries from 1990 to 2014. The main difficulty in assessing these impacts is the endogeneity of remittances and the difficulty in finding instruments to resolve this issue at the aggregate level. To address the endogeneity of remittances, I estimate bilateral remittances and use them to create weighted indicators of remittance-sending countries. These weighted indicators are used as instruments for remittance inflow to remittance-receiving countries. Results obtained in this study indicate that remittances decrease poverty. A 10% increase in per capita remittances leads to a 1% decrease in poverty headcount, 1.8% decrease in poverty gap, and 2.5% decrease in poverty headcount. Remittances also decrease inequality in developing countries. Remittances decrease the Gini coefficient, increase the income share held by the poorest decile and quintile, and decrease the income share held by the richest quintile and decile in developing countries.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
The reason that region dummies are used in this research rather than country dummies is that for many countries, there is just one year of data available, and for using country-specific effects, those countries had to be dropped from the regression. To avoid dropping those countries, I used region-specific effects rather that country-specific effects.
Ratha and Shaw (2007) propose a method of “Calculating Weights Based on Migrant Stocks, Per Capita Income in the Destination Countries, and Per Capita Income in the Source Countries”.
The average remittance sent by a migrant from host country j to home country i (\(r_{ij}\)) is modeled as a function of the per capita income of the home country and the host country.
$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle {r_{ij}=f(\overline{Y}_i Y_j)={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \overline{Y}_i &{}\quad \hbox {if} \ \ Y_j< \overline{Y}_i\\ \overline{Y}_i + (Y_j - \overline{Y}_i )^ \beta &{}\quad \text {otherwise} \end{array}\right. }} \end{aligned}$$where \(Y_j\) is the average per capita GNI of host country j, \(\overline{Y}_i\) is the per capita GNI of the migrant’s home country, and \(\beta \) is a parameter between 0 and 1. The amount sent by an average migrant is assumed to be at least as much as the per capita income of the home country, even when the individual migrates to a lower-income country. The rationale is that the migration occurs in the expectation of earning a higher level of income for the dependent household than what the migrant would earn in her home country. To estimate bilateral remittances for all countries, they use the average \(\beta \) (equal to 0.75) for the top 20 remittance-receiving countries. Then, for each home country i, \(r_{ij}\) is used to build weights for each host country j as
$$\begin{aligned} W_{ij}=\frac{r_{ij} M_{ij}}{\sum \nolimits _{j=1}^{214}{r_{ij} M_{ij}}}. \end{aligned}$$UN bilateral migration data includes just the following years: 1990, 1995, 2000, 2005, 2010, 2013, and 2015. I used linear interpolation to estimate bilateral migration for the remaining years. This should not raise any concerns as bilateral migration data, as well as GNI per capita of remittance-sending countries and GNI per capita of remittance-receiving countries, only are used to estimate bilateral remittances to use them as weights of remittance-sending countries in constructing weighted average economic variables of remittance-sending countries.
The estimated bilateral data consist of 214 remittance-receiving countries, 214 remittance-sending countries, and 1,190,696 observations.
References
Acharya CP, Leon-Gonzalez R (2014) How do migration and remittances affect human capital investment? The effects of relaxing information and liquidity constraints. J Dev Stud 50(3):444–460
Acosta P (2011) School attendance, child labour, and remittances from international migration in El Salvador. J Dev Stud 47(6):913–936
Acosta P, Calderón C, Fajnzylber P, López H (2006) Remittances and development in Latin America. World Econ 29(7):957–987
Acosta P, Calderon C, Fajnzylber P, Lopez H (2008) What is the impact of international remittances on poverty and inequality in Latin America? World Dev 36(1):89–114
Adams RH Jr (1989) Worker remittances and inequality in rural Egypt. Econ Dev Cult Change 38(1):45–71
Adams RH Jr, Cuecuecha A (2013) The impact of remittances on investment and poverty in Ghana. World Dev 50:24–40
Adams RH, Mahmood Z (1992) The effects of migration and remittances on inequality in rural Pakistan [with Comments]. Pak Dev Rev 31(4):1189–1206
Adams RH, Page J (2005) Do international migration and remittances reduce poverty in developing countries? World Dev 33(10):1645–1669
Adams R, Lopez-Feldman A, Mora J, Taylor JE (2008) Remittances, inequality and poverty: evidence from rural Mexico. In: DeWind J, Holdaway J (eds) Migration and development within and across borders: research and policy perspectives on internal and international migration. International Organization for Migration, Geneva, pp 101–130
Adeniyi O, Ajide K, Raheem ID (2019) Remittances and output growth volatility in developing countries: does financial development dampen or magnify the effects? Empir Econ 56(3):865–882
Aggarwal R, Peria MSM (2006) Do workers’ remittances promote financial development? vol 3957. World Bank Publications, Washington
Aggarwal R, Demirgüç-Kunt A, Peria MSM (2011) Do remittances promote financial development? J Dev Econ 96(2):255–264
Anyanwu JC (2011) International remittances and income inequality in Africa. Rev Econ Bus Stud 7(5):117–148
Azizi S (2017) Altruism: primary motivation of remittances. Appl Econ Lett 24(17):1218–1221
Azizi S (2018) The impacts of workers’ remittances on human capital and labor supply in developing countries. Econ Model 75:377–396
Azizi S (2019) Why do migrants remit? World Econ 42(2):429–452
Bang JT, Mitra A, Wunnava PV (2016) Do remittances improve income inequality? An instrumental variable quantile analysis of the Kenyan case. Econ Model 58:394–402
Barajas A, Gapen MT, Chami R, Montiel P, Fullenkamp C (2009) Do workers’ remittances promote economic growth? (No. 2009–2153). International Monetary Fund
Bang JT, Mandal A, Mitra (2019) A transnational remittances and state protection of human rights: a case for caution. Econ Notes. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecno.12147
Barham B, Boucher S (1998) Migration, remittances, and inequality: estimating the net effects of migration on income distribution. J Dev Econ 55(2):307–331
Bettin G, Presbitero AF, Spatafora NL (2015) Remittances and vulnerability in developing countries. World Bank Econ Rev 31(1):1–23
Bertoli S, Marchetta F (2014) Migration, remittances and poverty in Ecuador. J Dev Stud 50(8):1067–1089
Beyene BM (2014) The effects of international remittances on poverty and inequality in Ethiopia. J Dev Stud 50(10):1380–1396
Bollard A, McKenzie D, Morten M, Rapoport H (2011) Remittances and the brain drain revisited: the microdata show that more educated migrants remit more. World Bank Econ Rev 25(1):132–156
Chami R, Fullenkamp C, Gapen M (2009a) Measuring workers’ remittances: what should be kept in and what should be left out. International Monetary Fund, Mimeo
Chami R, Hakura D, Montiel PJ (2009b) Remittances: an automatic output stabilizer? (No. 9-91). International Monetary Fund
Chauvet L, Gubert F, Mesple-Somps S (2013) Aid, remittances, medical brain drain and child mortality: evidence using inter and intra-country data. J Dev Stud 49(6):801–818
Combes JL, Ebeke CH, Maurel M, Yogo TU (2014) Remittances and working poverty. J Dev Stud 50(10):1348–1361
Docquier F, Rapoport H, Salomone S (2012) Remittances, migrants’ education and immigration policy: theory and evidence from bilateral data. Region Sci Urban Econ 42(5):817–828
Faini R (2007) Remittances and the brain drain: do more skilled migrants remit more? World Bank Econ Rev 21(2):177–191
Ebeke CH (2012) Do remittances lead to a public moral hazard in developing countries? An empirical investigation. J Dev Stud 48(8):1009–1025
Feeny S, Iamsiraroj S, McGillivray M (2014) Remittances and economic growth: larger impacts in smaller countries? J Dev Stud 50(8):1055–1066
Frankel J (2011) Are bilateral remittances countercyclical? Open Econ Rev 22(1):1–16
Freund C, Spatafora N (2008) Remittances, transaction costs, and informality. J Dev Econ 86(2):356–366
Gupta S, Pattillo CA, Wagh S (2009) Effect of remittances on poverty and financial development in Sub-Saharan Africa. World Dev 37(1):104–115
IMF (2009) International transactions in remittances: guide for compilers and users
Jimenez-Soto EV, Brown RP (2012) Assessing the poverty impacts of migrants’ remittances using propensity score matching: the case of Tonga. Econ Record 88(282):425–439
Johansen S (1988) Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. J Econ Dyn Control 12(2–3):231–254
Kao C (1999) Spurious regression and residual-based tests for cointegration in panel data. J Econom 90(1):1–44
Konte M (2018) Do remittances not promote growth? A finite mixture-of-regressions approach. Empir Econ 54(2):747–782
Le De L, Gaillard JC, Friesen W (2015) Poverty and disasters: do remittances reproduce vulnerability? J Dev Stud 51(5):538–553
Lueth E, Ruiz-Arranz M (2008) Determinants of bilateral remittance flows. BE J Macroecon 8(1):1–23
Melkonyan TA, Grigorian DA (2012) Microeconomic implications of remittances in an overlapping generations model with altruism and a motive to receive inheritance. J Dev Stud 48(8):1026–1044
Ratha D (2005) Workers’ remittances: an important and stable source of external development finance. In: Remittances: development impact and future prospects. World Bank, pp 19–51
Ratha D, Shaw W (2007) South-South migration and remittances. World Bank Publications (No. 102)
Ruiz I, Vargas-Silva C (2012) Exploring the causes of the slowdown in remittances to Mexico. Empir Econ 42(3):745–766
Siddique A, Selvanathan EA, Selvanathan S (2012) Remittances and economic growth: empirical evidence from Bangladesh, India and Sri Lanka. J Dev Stud 48(8):1045–1062
Stark O, Taylor JE, Yitzhaki S (1986) Remittances and inequality. Econ J 96(383):722–740
Stark O, Taylor JE, Yitzhaki S (1988) Migration, remittances and inequality: a sensitivity analysis using the extended Gini index. J Dev Econ 28(3):309–322
Taylor JE, Wyatt TJ (1996) The shadow value of migrant remittances, income and inequality in a household-farm economy. J Dev Stud 32(6):899–912
Terrelonge SC (2014) For health, strength, and daily food: the dual impact of remittances and public health expenditure on household health spending and child health outcomes. J Dev Stud 50(10):1397–1410
Yang D, Choi H (2007) Are remittances insurance? Evidence from rainfall shocks in the Philippines. World Bank Econ Rev 21(2):219–248
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Conflict of interest
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendices
Appendix A
See Table 7.
Appendix B
The results of the first-stage regressions are provided in Table 8. The dependent variable is the logarithm of per capita remittances. The explanatory variables are weighted average per capita GNI, unemployment rate, real interest rate, real exchange rate, and labor force participation rate of the remittance-sending countries. In each first-stage regression, the endogenous variable (per capita remittances) is regressed on all instruments and all exogenous variables of the original regression. In each first-stage regression, I test the joint significance of five instruments. The F-values are reported in the table. The rule of thumb is that if the F-value is greater than 10, then the instrument is strong.
The first column of Table 8 shows the result of the first-stage regression for original regressions with poverty measures as the dependent variables. The second column of Table 8 shows the result of the first-stage regression for original regressions with the Gini coefficient as the dependent variable and per capita GDP, inflation, broad money, and per capita FDI as control variables. This column also represents the results of the first-stage regression for the regressions provided in Table 6. The third column of Table 8 shows the result of the first-stage regression for original regressions with the Gini coefficient as the dependent variable and per capita GDP, broad money, and per capita FDI as control variables. The fourth column of Table 8 shows the results of the first-stage regression for original regressions with the Gini coefficient as the dependent variable and per capita GDP and broad money as control variables.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Azizi, S. The impacts of workers’ remittances on poverty and inequality in developing countries. Empir Econ 60, 969–991 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01764-8
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01764-8